Riparian Rights from Another Standpoint [pp. 10-14]

Overland monthly and Out West magazine. / Volume 6, Issue 31

Riparian Rights from another Standpoint. of the riparian owners between them and the stream, but because of the rights and for the benefit of the hundreds of owners of lands below upon the stream. Were the ripa rian owners between them and the stream to assent, the diversion could not be accom plished, because it would involve injury to those hundreds below. Nor are the owners of the outlying tracts without benefit from the riparian doctrine. So far as their lands are in the river plain, and are naturally irri gated by the seepage or percolation through the soil of water from the stream, they have riparian rights. Were all the owners of lands upon the banks of the stream to consent to the diversion of all the water of the stream at a point above, these owners of outlying tracts would have a remedy, in case, through the cessation of natural irrigation through the soil, their lands were rendered appreciably dry and less fruitful. The provisions of the civil code of California (pp. I4IO, I422), while they cannot authorize an interference with riparian rights, and therefore cannot authorize the appropriation of waters ordinarily flowing down our streams during the summer months, are adapted to enable the appropriation of the flood waters of our rivers and their storage in reservoirs in the canions in the Sierra Nevadas. The riparian owner has no property in the water. His right is confined to the advantages he derives from the ordinary flow of the stream. In the absence of such provisions, no company could dam up and thus appropriate flood waters with any assurance that they might not be deprived of the same at any moment. If the State so desires, it may convert the right to reservoir these waters and to distribute them to the valley lands into a privilege subject to conditions imposed by the State, and subject to regulation as to water rates exacted, and as to facilities extended to the agricultural districts. Thereby many of the abuses which might otherwise spring from the private control of the means of artificial irrigation may be prevented. If the State sees fit, the State may itself proceed to build, at its own expense, dams and ditches, and to operate the same. But private enterprise would probably ac complish the desired end with greater cer tainty and efficiency and at less expense. In this connection, it is to be noticed that the abolition of riparian rights, if it could be ac complished, would leave the waters open to appropriation, and the valuable property would inevitably fall to the strongest, that is into the hands of private monopolies. If the State should attempt to manage its waters through its governmental machinery, as public property, a paternal element would be introduced into the State. Such an element is especially dangerous, when we consider that in proportion as the adminis tration partakes of that character can the State be converted to the purpose of com munism with greater ease. The State would have appropriated property claimed by individuals, and would be administering it for the so-called good of all. What better precedent is needed for the progressive encroachment upon the rights of individuals for the assumed good of all? What greater aid can be given to those who seek to use the State to a paternal or communistic end, than can be given by creating a large class of government employees, engaged in the management of governmental works of great magnitude, and a large attendant class seeking for governmental employment, and eager to enlarge the industrial activity of the State in order to increase the number of its employees? The unsuitableness to our country of the laws of France, Italy and other states, relating to water, consists in the intensely paternal government required for their administration. The true course for the State is to protect vested rights by recognizing the water rights of riparian owners; to provide for their condemnation, if necessary, to the public use; and to authorize the appropriation of the flood waters by private companies and corporations, not in absolute property, but in pursuance of a privilege extended by the State and subject in its enjoyment to State regulation. Thereby rights will be protected, monopolies prevented, and yet all progress towards a paternal government be avoided. John i[ Durst. [July, 14

/ 118
Pages Index

Actions

file_download Download Options Download this page PDF - Pages 5-14 Image - Page 14 Plain Text - Page 14

About this Item

Title
Riparian Rights from Another Standpoint [pp. 10-14]
Author
Durst, John H.
Canvas
Page 14
Serial
Overland monthly and Out West magazine. / Volume 6, Issue 31

Technical Details

Link to this Item
https://name.umdl.umich.edu/ahj1472.2-06.031
Link to this scan
https://quod.lib.umich.edu/m/moajrnl/ahj1472.2-06.031/20:4

Rights and Permissions

The University of Michigan Library provides access to these materials for educational and research purposes. These materials are in the public domain in the United States. If you have questions about the collection, please contact Digital Content & Collections at [email protected]. If you have concerns about the inclusion of an item in this collection, please contact Library Information Technology at [email protected].

DPLA Rights Statement: No Copyright - United States

Manifest
https://quod.lib.umich.edu/cgi/t/text/api/manifest/moajrnl:ahj1472.2-06.031

Cite this Item

Full citation
"Riparian Rights from Another Standpoint [pp. 10-14]." In the digital collection Making of America Journal Articles. https://name.umdl.umich.edu/ahj1472.2-06.031. University of Michigan Library Digital Collections. Accessed June 24, 2025.
Do you have questions about this content? Need to report a problem? Please contact us.