The Costs of Free Education-A View from California WHAT PRICE ZERO TUITION? By ARMEN A. ALCHIAN and WILLIAM R. ALLEN INCE the fiasco in the Garden of Eden, mankind has suffered from scarcity: there cannot be enough goods and services to satisfy completely all the wants of all the people all the time. Consequently, man has had to learn the hard way that, in order to obtain more of this good, he must forego some of that: most goods carry a price, and obtaining them involves the bearing of a cost. Poets assure us that the best things in life are free. If so, education is a second-best good, for it decidedly is not free. But if education is not free, if a price must be paid, who is to pay it? By developed instinct, the economist initially presumes it to be appropriate that payment of the price should be made by those who receive the good. "Those who get should pay" is a strong rule of thumb; the economist will deviate from it only for profoundly compelling reasons. But general economic theory does not assert that we must charge tuition to allocate resources and distribute educational goods; nor does economic theory tell us that zero tuition is best. And, of course, there is an infinitude of alternatives between all or nothing. Zero tuition means a public subsidy-a system of individually non-voluntary gifts from the community at large to the recipients. And, as with any system of subsidy, we may ask why this particular group is to be subsidized, what members of the group, to The authors are colleagues in the Department of Economics at The University of California, Los Angeles, of which PROFESSOR ALLEN is chairman. PROFESSOR ALCHIAN is an active consultant to government and industry. Both have received numererous awards, and have published widely. Together they have written University Economics (1964, 1967). what extent and in what manner, and what, precisely, is the substance of the gift. In the California system of zero tuition1 in the university and state colleges, the particularized gifts go to a small portion of a select group. The community has singled out a few of its members as eligible for the gift of some expenses paid at certain schools. Not everyone can receive the gift, and those who do receive it must take it only as zero tuition in a public college in California. Now, such selective and closely specified subsidization may be the very best use we can devise for these resources of the community. But the mere fact of its selectivity, which is not uniform everywhere and at all times, creates some small doubt that zero tuition is certainly the optimal scheme. Are we sure-indeed, has there been general and appreciable concern-that subsidization of college students is the best use of 0Our discussion stems most immediately from the continuing controversy in California over proposed tuition in the state university and the several state colleges. In those institutions, no tuition has been charged state residents, but various "fees" total nearly $250 per year for the university and about $130 for the colleges (non-residents are now charged a tuition of $1200 by the university and some $770 by the colleges). In January 1967, newly elected Governor Ronald Reagan suggested tuition charges of $400 and $200 for the university and the colleges, respectively; shortly thereafter, he proposed the more modest charges of $250-280 and $150-160 (in addition to existing fees). In late summer 1967, the university Board of Regents rejected the tuition proposal-but agreed to raise "fees" by an amount to be determined later. A survey by the University of Oregon in November 1966 (many have since been raised) includes the following data for fees-plus-tuition for undergraduate state-residents in state universities: New York $500 Indiana $330 Ohio 459 Oregon 330 Minnesota 375 North Carolina 303 Michigan 348 Texas 156 269 0
Top of page Top of page